Items related to Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence:...

Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence: Theory and Evidence - Second Edition - Hardcover

 
9780691161648: Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence: Theory and Evidence - Second Edition

Synopsis

Trade is a cornerstone concept in economics worldwide. This updated second edition of the essential graduate textbook in international trade brings readers to the forefront of knowledge in the field and prepares students to undertake their own research. In Advanced International Trade, Robert Feenstra integrates the most current theoretical approaches with empirical evidence, and these materials are supplemented in each chapter by theoretical and empirical exercises. Feenstra explores a wealth of material, such as the Ricardian and Heckscher-Ohlin models, extensions to many goods and factors, and the role of tariffs, quotas, and other trade policies. He examines imperfect competition, offshoring, political economy, multinationals, endogenous growth, the gravity equation, and the organization of the firm in international trade. Feenstra also includes a new chapter on monopolistic competition with heterogeneous firms, with many applications of that model. In addition to known results, the book looks at some particularly important unpublished results by various authors. Two appendices draw on index numbers and discrete choice models to describe methods applicable to research problems in international trade. Completely revised with the latest developments and brand-new materials, Advanced International Trade is a classic textbook that will be used widely by students and practitioners of economics for a long time to come. * Updated second edition of the essential graduate textbook* Current approaches and a new chapter on monopolistic competition with heterogeneous firms* Supplementary materials in each chapter* Theoretical and empirical exercises* Two appendices describe methods for international trade research

"synopsis" may belong to another edition of this title.

About the Author

Robert C. Feenstra is a professor in the Department of Economics at the University of California, Davis, where he holds the C. Bryan Cameron Distinguished Chair in International Economics. His books include Offshoring in the Global Economy and Product Variety and the Gains from International Trade.

From the Back Cover

Praise for the previous editon: "No other book in advanced international trade matches this one in providing a clear, complete, up-to-date, balanced, and systematic summary of international trade theory and evidence. Its impact on the graduate education and scholarly research of international trade will be felt for years to come."--Bin Xu, University of Florida

Praise for the previous editon: "In fifteen years of teaching this material I have never used a textbook. Thanks to Robert Feenstra, my students are about to experience a dramatic change for the better. When I have a question about international trade I immediately turn to Rob Feenstra for answers and insights. He is the most distinguished empirical researcher in the field today. Not surprisingly, this book reflects both his awesome scholarship and his ability to communicate ideas simply."--Daniel Trefler, University of Toronto

Praise for the previous editon: "This book is a tremendous contribution. It will quickly become 'the' main textbook in graduate international trade classes, and will be a useful reference for many others interested in the field. It is very up-to-date and is unique in emphasizing empirical testing and results, precisely what most trade economists are doing these days."--Douglas Irwin, Dartmouth College, author of Free Trade Under Fire

Praise for the previous editon: "Feenstra covers his topics fabulously. I hope--for the sake of our field--that this book will help to complete a revolution already underway in turning the study of international trade from speculation into a science."--Donald Davis, Columbia University

Praise for the previous editon: "Robert Feenstra is to be congratulated on producing this excellent book, which should be on the bookshelf of anyone interested in trade theory and empirical research on international trade."--Sisira Jayasuriya, Economic Record

Excerpt. © Reprinted by permission. All rights reserved.

Advanced International Trade

Theory and Evidence

By Robert C. Feenstra

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS

Copyright © 2016 Princeton University Press
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-0-691-16164-8

Contents

Acknowledgments, ix,
Foreword to the Second Edition, xi,
Chapter 1 Preliminaries: Two-Sector Models, 1,
Chapter 2 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model, 25,
Chapter 3 Many Goods and Factors, 51,
Chapter 4 Trade in Intermediate Inputs and Wages, 83,
Chapter 5 Monopolistic Competition and the Gravity Equation I, 119,
Chapter 6 Monopolistic Competition and the Gravity Equation II, 155,
Chapter 7 Gains from Trade and Regional Agreements, 186,
Chapter 8 Import Tariffs and Dumping, 214,
Chapter 9 Import Quotas and Export Subsidies, 256,
Chapter 10 Political Economy of Trade Policy, 299,
Chapter 11 Trade and Endogenous Growth, 331,
Chapter 12 Multinationals and Organization of the Firm, 360,
Appendix A Price, Productivity, and Terms of Trade Indexes, 403,
Appendix B Discrete Choice Models, 419,
References, 431,
Index, 465,


CHAPTER 1

Preliminaries: Two-Sector Models


We begin our study of international trade with the classic Ricardian model, which has two goods and one factor (labor). The Ricardian model introduces us to the idea that technological differences across countries matter. In comparison, the Heckscher-Ohlin model dispenses with the notion of technological differences and instead shows how factor endowments form the basis for trade. While this may be fine in theory, the model performs very poorly in practice: as we show in the next chapter, the Heckscher-Ohlin model is hopelessly inadequate as an explanation for historical or modern trade patterns unless we allow for technological differences across countries. For this reason, the Ricardian model is as relevant today as it has always been. Our treatment of it in this chapter is a simple review of undergraduate material, but we will present a more sophisticated version of the Ricardian model (with a continuum of goods) in chapter 3.

After reviewing the Ricardian model, we turn to the two-good, two-factor model that occupies most of this chapter and forms the basis of the Heckscher-Ohlin model. We shall suppose that the two goods are traded on international markets, but do not allow for any movements of factors across borders. This reflects the fact that the movement of labor and capital across countries is often subject to controls at the border and is generally much less free than the movement of goods. Our goal in the next chapter will be to determine the pattern of international trade between countries. In this chapter, we simplify things by focusing primarily on one country, treating world prices as given, and examine the properties of this two- by-two model. The student who understands all the properties of this model has already come a long way in his or her study of international trade.


RICARDIAN MODEL

Indexing goods by the subscript i, let ai denote the labor needed per unit of production of each good at home, while a*i is the labor need per unit of production in the foreign country, i =1, 2. The total labor force at home is L and abroad is L* . Labor is perfectly mobile between the industries in each country, but immobile across countries. This means that both goods are produced in the home country only if the wages earned in the two industries are the same. Since the marginal product of labor in each industry is 1/ai, and workers are paid the value of their marginal products, wages are equalized across industries if and only if p1/a1 = p2/a2/a2, where p1 is the price in each industry. Letting p = p1/p2 denote the relative price of good 1(using good 2 as the numeraire), this condition is p = a1/a2.

These results are illustrated in figure 1.1(a) and (b), where we graph the production possibility frontiers (PPFs) for the home and foreign countries. With all labor devoted to good i at home, it can produce L/ai units, i =1, 2, so this establishes the intercepts of the PPF, and similarly for the foreign country. The slope of the PPF in each country (ignoring the negative sign) is then a1/a2 and a1)/a2). Under autarky (i.e., no international trade), the equilibrium relative prices pa and pa*) must equal these slopes in order to have both goods produced in both countries, as argued above. Thus, the autarky equilibrium at home and abroad might occur at points A and A* Suppose that the home country has a comparative advantage in producing good 1, meaning that a1/a2< a1*/a2*). This implies that the home autarky relative price of good 1 is lower than that abroad.

Now letting the two countries engage in international trade, what is the equilibrium price p at which world demand equals world supply? To answer this, it is helpful to graph the world relative supply and demand curves, as illustrated in figure 1.2. For the relative price satisfying p< pa = a1/a2 and pa* = pa*< a1* /a2* both countries are fully specialized in good 2 (since wages earned in that sector are higher), so the world relative supply of good 1 is zero. For pa< p< pa), the home country is fully specialized in good 1 whereas the foreign country is still specialized in good 2, so that the world relative supply is L/a1)/(L*/a*2)), as labeled in figure 1.2. Finally, for p >pa and p >pa), both countries are specialized in good 1. So we see that the world relative supply curve has a "stair-step" shape, which reflects the linearity of the PPFs.

To obtain world relative demand, let us make the simplifying assumption that tastes are identical and homothetic across the countries. Then demand will be independent of the distribution of income across the countries. Demand being homothetic means that relative demand d1/d2 in either country is a downward-sloping function of the relative price p, as illustrated in figure 1.2. In the case we have shown, relative demand intersects relative supply at the world price p that lies between pa and pa*, but this does not need to occur: instead, we can have relative demand intersect one of the flat segments of relative supply, so that the equilibrium price with trade equals the autarky price in one country.

Focusing on the case where pa< p< pa*), we can go back to the PPF of each country and graph the production and consumption points with free trade. Since p >pa, the home country is fully specialized in good at point B* as illustrated in figure 1.1(a), and then trades at the relative price p to obtain consumption at point C*. Conversely, since p< pa, the foreign country is fully specialized in the production of good 2 at point B in figure 1.1(b), and then trades at the relative price p to obtain consumption at point C. Clearly, both countries are better off under free trade than they were in autarky: trade has allowed them to obtain a consumption point that is above the PPF.

Notice that the home country exports good 1, which is in keeping with its comparative advantage in the production of that good, a1/a2< a*1/ a*2. Thus, trade patterns are determined by comparative advantage, which is a deep insight from the Ricardian model. This occurs even if one country has an absolute disadvantage in both goods, such as a1 >a*1 and a2 >a*2, so that more labor is needed per unit of production of either good at home than abroad. The reason that it is still possible for the home country to export is that its wages will adjust to reflect its productivities: under free trade, its wages are lower than those abroad. Thus, while trade patterns in the Ricardian model are determined by comparative advantage, the level of wages across countries is determined by absolute advantage.


TWO-GOOD, TWO-FACTOR MODEL

While the Ricardian model focuses on technology, the Heckscher-Ohlin model, which we study in the next chapter, focuses on factors of production. So we now assume that there are two factor inputs — labor and capital. Restricting our attention to a single country, we will suppose that it produces two goods with the production functions yi = fi(Li,Ki,[i = 1, 2, where yi is the output produced using labor Li and capital Ki These production functions are assumed to be increasing, concave, and homogeneous of degree one in the inputs (Li,Ki). The last assumption means that there are constant returns to scale in the production of each good. This will be a maintained assumption for the next several chapters, but we should be point out that it is rather restrictive. It has long been thought that increasing returns to scale might be an important reason to have trade between countries: if a firm with increasing returns is able to sell in a foreign market, this expansion of output will bring a reduction in its average costs of production, which is an indication of greater efficiency. Indeed, this was a principal reason why Canada entered into a free-trade agreement with the United States in 1989: to give its firms free access to the large American market. We will return to these interesting issues in chapter 5, but for now, ignore increasing returns to scale.

We will assume that labor and capital are fully mobile between the two industries, so we are taking a "long run" point of view. Of course, the amount of factors employed in each industry is constrained by the endowments found in the economy. These resource constraints are stated as

L1 + L2 ≤ L, K1 + K2 ≤ K. (1.1)


where the endowments L and K are fixed. Maximizing the amount of good 2, y2 = f2 (L2, K2, subject to a given amount of good 1, y1, = L(f1) (L1 [K1), and the resource constraints in (1.1) give us y2 = h(y1), L1K1). The graph of y2 as a function of y1 is shown as the PPF in figure 1.3. As drawn, y2 is a concave function of y1, [partial derivative]2h(y1, L,K) [partial derivative] y12< 0. This familiar result follows from the fact that the production functions fi (Li, Ki) are assumed to be concave. Another way to express this is to consider all points S =(y1), y2 that are feasible to produce given the resource constraints in (1.1). This production possibilities set S is convex, meaning that if ya=(y1a, ya and y1b = yb, yb) are both elements of S, then any point between them λ ya +(1-λ) yb is also in S, for 0 [less than or equal to] λ ≤ 1.

The production possibilities frontier summarizes the technology of the economy, but in order to determine where the economy produces on the PPF we need to add some assumptions about the market structure. We will assume perfect competition in the product markets and factor markets. Furthermore, we will suppose that product prices are given exogenously: we can think of these prices as established on world markets, and outside the control of the "small" country being considered.


GDP FUNCTION

With the assumption of perfect competition, the amounts produced in each industry will maximize gross domestic product (GDP) for the economy: this is Adam Smith's "invisible hand" in action. That is, the industry outputs of the competitive economy will be chosen to maximize GDP:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1.2)

To solve this problem, we can substitute the constraint into the objective function and write it as choosing y1 to maximize p1y1 + p2h(y1, L, K). The first-order condition for this problem is p1 + p2 [partial derivative] h /[partial derivative] y1= 0, or,

p = p1/p2 = - [partial derivative] h/[partial derivative]hy1 = - [partial derivative]y2/[partial derivative]y1. (1.3)

Thus, the economy will produce where the relative price of good 1, p = p1/p2, is equal to the slope of the production possibilities frontier.5 This is illustrated by the point A in figure 1.4, where the line tangent through point A has the slope of (negative) p. An increase in this price will raise the slope of this line, leading to a new tangency at point B. As illustrated, then, the economy will produce more of good 1 and less of good 2.

The GDP function introduced in (1.2) has many convenient properties, and we will make use of it throughout this book. To show just one property, suppose that we differentiate the GDP function with respect to the price of good i, obtaining It turns out that the terms in parentheses on the right of (1.4) sum to zero, so that [partial derivative]G/[partial derivative]pi = yi. In other words, the derivative of the GDP function with respect to prices equals the outputs of the economy.

The fact that the terms in parentheses sum to zero is an application of the "envelope theorem," which states that when we differentiate a function that has been maximized (such as GDP) with respect to an exogenous variable (such as pi), then we can ignore the changes in the endogenous variables (y1 and y2) in this derivative. To prove that these terms sum to zero, totally differentiate y2 = h(y1, L,K] with respect to y1 and y2 and use (1.3) to obtain p1dy1 = - p2dy2, or p1dy1+ p2dy2 = 0 This equality must hold for any small movement in y1 and y2 around the PPF, and in particular, for the small movement in outputs induced by the change in pi. In other words, p1([partial derivative] y1/[partial derivative] p1)+ p2([partial derivative]y2/ [partial derivative] p1) = 0, so the terms in parentheses on the right of (1.4) vanish and it follows that [partial derivative]G/ [partial derivative] p1 = y1.


EQUILIBRIUM CONDITIONS

We now want to state succinctly the equilibrium conditions to determine factor prices and outputs. It will be convenient to work with the unit-cost functions that are dual to the production functions (fi Li,Ki). These are defined by.


(Continues...)
Excerpted from Advanced International Trade by Robert C. Feenstra. Copyright © 2016 Princeton University Press. Excerpted by permission of PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

"About this title" may belong to another edition of this title.

Buy Used

Condition: Very Good
The book has been read, but is...
View this item

£ 2.80 shipping within United Kingdom

Destination, rates & speeds

Buy New

View this item

£ 14.81 shipping from U.S.A. to United Kingdom

Destination, rates & speeds

Search results for Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence:...

Stock Image

Feenstra, Robert C.
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
Used Paperback

Seller: WorldofBooks, Goring-By-Sea, WS, United Kingdom

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Paperback. Condition: Very Good. The book has been read, but is in excellent condition. Pages are intact and not marred by notes or highlighting. The spine remains undamaged. Seller Inventory # GOR010520695

Contact seller

Buy Used

£ 43.28
Convert currency
Shipping: £ 2.80
Within United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 1 available

Add to basket

Stock Image

Feenstra, Robert C.
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
New Hardcover

Seller: Labyrinth Books, Princeton, NJ, U.S.A.

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Condition: New. Seller Inventory # 187107

Contact seller

Buy New

£ 44.21
Convert currency
Shipping: £ 14.81
From U.S.A. to United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 6 available

Add to basket

Stock Image

Feenstra, Robert C.
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
Used Hardcover

Seller: Better World Books, Mishawaka, IN, U.S.A.

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Condition: As New. Used book that is in almost brand-new condition. Seller Inventory # 52578397-6

Contact seller

Buy Used

£ 51.97
Convert currency
Shipping: £ 7.09
From U.S.A. to United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 1 available

Add to basket

Stock Image

Feenstra, Robert C.
Published by Princeton University Press, 2016
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
Used Hardcover

Seller: Anybook.com, Lincoln, United Kingdom

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Condition: Good. This is an ex-library book and may have the usual library/used-book markings inside.This book has hardback covers. In good all round condition. Please note the Image in this listing is a stock photo and may not match the covers of the actual item,1100grams, ISBN:9780691161648. Seller Inventory # 5578844

Contact seller

Buy Used

£ 59.71
Convert currency
Shipping: £ 4.48
Within United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 1 available

Add to basket

Stock Image

Feenstra, Robert C.
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
Used Hardcover

Seller: medimops, Berlin, Germany

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Condition: good. Befriedigend/Good: Durchschnittlich erhaltenes Buch bzw. Schutzumschlag mit Gebrauchsspuren, aber vollständigen Seiten. / Describes the average WORN book or dust jacket that has all the pages present. Seller Inventory # M0069116164X-G

Contact seller

Buy Used

£ 62.22
Convert currency
Shipping: £ 3.04
From Germany to United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 1 available

Add to basket

Seller Image

Feenstra, Robert C.
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
New Hardcover

Seller: GreatBookPricesUK, Woodford Green, United Kingdom

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Condition: New. Seller Inventory # 23910603-n

Contact seller

Buy New

£ 68.30
Convert currency
Shipping: FREE
Within United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: Over 20 available

Add to basket

Stock Image

Robert C. Feenstra
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
New Hardcover

Seller: PBShop.store UK, Fairford, GLOS, United Kingdom

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

HRD. Condition: New. New Book. Shipped from UK. Established seller since 2000. Seller Inventory # WP-9780691161648

Contact seller

Buy New

£ 68.31
Convert currency
Shipping: FREE
Within United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 15 available

Add to basket

Stock Image

FEENSTRA, ROBERT
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
New Hardcover

Seller: Speedyhen, London, United Kingdom

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Condition: NEW. Seller Inventory # NW9780691161648

Contact seller

Buy New

£ 68.75
Convert currency
Shipping: FREE
Within United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 2 available

Add to basket

Stock Image

Robert C. Feenstra
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
New Hardcover

Seller: PBShop.store US, Wood Dale, IL, U.S.A.

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

HRD. Condition: New. New Book. Shipped from UK. Established seller since 2000. Seller Inventory # WP-9780691161648

Contact seller

Buy New

£ 76.19
Convert currency
Shipping: FREE
From U.S.A. to United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: 15 available

Add to basket

Seller Image

Feenstra, Robert C.
Published by Princeton University Press, 2015
ISBN 10: 069116164X ISBN 13: 9780691161648
Used Hardcover

Seller: GreatBookPricesUK, Woodford Green, United Kingdom

Seller rating 5 out of 5 stars 5-star rating, Learn more about seller ratings

Condition: As New. Unread book in perfect condition. Seller Inventory # 23910603

Contact seller

Buy Used

£ 79.80
Convert currency
Shipping: FREE
Within United Kingdom
Destination, rates & speeds

Quantity: Over 20 available

Add to basket

There are 22 more copies of this book

View all search results for this book